Ludwig von Mises
"Economics deals with society's fundamental problems; it concerns everyone and belongs to all. It is the main and proper study of every citizen."
—Ludwig von Mises, Human Action
Ludwig Heinrich Edler von Mises (29 September 1881–10 October 1973) was one of the most notable economists and social philosophers of the twentieth century. In the course of a long and highly productive life, he developed an integrated, deductive science of economics based on the fundamental axiom that individual human beings act purposively to achieve desired goals. Even though his economic analysis itself was "value-free" — in the sense of being irrelevant to values held by economists — Mises concluded that the only viable economic policy for the human race was a policy of unrestricted laissez-faire, of free markets and the unhampered exercise of the right of private property, with government strictly limited to the defense of person and property within its territorial area.
For Mises was able to demonstrate (a) that the expansion of free markets, the division of labor, and private capital investment is the only possible path to the prosperity and flourishing of the human race; (b) that socialism would be disastrous for a modern economy because the absence of private ownership of land and capital goods prevents any sort of rational pricing, or estimate of costs, and (c) that government intervention, in addition to hampering and crippling the market, would prove counter-productive and cumulative, leading inevitably to socialism unless the entire tissue of interventions was repealed.
Holding these views, and hewing to truth indomitably in the face of a century increasingly devoted to statism and collectivism, Mises became famous for his "intransigence" in insisting on a non-inflationary gold standard and on laissez-faire.
Effectively barred from any paid university post in Austria and later in the United States, Mises pursued his course gallantly. As the chief economic adviser to the Austrian government in the 1920s, Mises was, with the help of Chancellor Ignaz Seipel,[1] able to slow down Austrian inflation; and he developed his own "private seminar" which attracted the outstanding young economists, social scientists, and philosophers throughout Europe. As the founder of the "neo-Austrian School" of economics, Mises’s business cycle theory, which blamed inflation and depressions on inflationary bank credit encouraged by Central Banks, was adopted by most younger economists in England in the early 1930s as the best explanation of the Great Depression.
Having fled the Nazis to the United States, Mises did some of his most important work here. In over two decades of teaching, he inspired an emerging Austrian School in the United States. The year after Mises died in 1973, his most distinguished follower, F.A. Hayek, was awarded the Nobel Prize in economics for his work in elaborating Mises’s business cycle theory during the later 1920s and 1930s.
Contents
Early life

Mises was born on Sept 29, 1881, in the city of Lemberg (now Lvov) in Galicia, where his father, a Viennese construction engineer working for the Austrian railroads, was then stationed. Both Mises’s father and mother came from prominent Viennese families; his mother’s uncle, Dr Joachim Landau, served as deputy from the Liberal Party in the Austrian Parliament.
Entering the University of Vienna at the turn of the century as a leftist interventionist, the young Mises discovered Principles of Economics (text, pdf) by Carl Menger, the founding work of the Austrian School of economics, and was quickly converted to the Austrian emphasis on individual action rather than unrealistic mechanistic equations as the unit of economics analysis, and to the importance of a free-market economy.
Mises became a prominent post-doctoral student in the famous University of Vienna seminar of the great Austrian economist Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk (among whose many accomplishments was the devastating refutation of the Marxian labor theory of value).
The Mises Institute's coat of arms (see full view) is that of the Mises family, awarded in 1881 when Ludwig von Mises's great-grandfather Mayer Rachmiel Mises was ennobled by the Emperor Franz Josef I of Austria. In the upper right-hand quadrant is the staff of Mercury, god of commerce and communication (the Mises family was successful in both; they were merchants and bankers). In the lower left-hand quadrant is a representation of the Ten Commandments. Mayer Rachmiel, as well as his father, presided over various Jewish cultural organizations in Lemberg, the city where Ludwig was born. The red banner displays the Rose of Sharon, which in the litany is one of the names given to the Blessed Mother, as well as the Stars of the Royal House of David, a symbol of the Jewish people. Ludwig's lifelong motto was from Virgil: tu ne cede malis, sed contra audentior ito ("do not give in to evil, but proceed ever more boldly against it").
Professional life
During this period, in his first great work, The Theory of Money and Credit(1912) (text, pdf) Mises performed what had been deemed an impossible task: to integrate the theory of money into the general theory of marginal utility and price (what would now be called integrating "macroeconomics" into "microeconomics"). Since Bohm-Bawerk and his other Austrian colleagues did not accept Mises’s integration and remained without a monetary theory, he was therefore obliged to strike out on his own and found a "neo-Austrian" school.
In his monetary theory, Mises revived the long forgotten British Currency School principle, prominent until the 1850s, that society does not at all benefit from any increase in the money supply, that increased money and bank credit only causes inflation and business cycles, and that therefore government policy should maintain the equivalent of a 100 percent gold standard.
Mises added to this insight the elements of his business cycle theory: that credit expansion by the banks, in addition to causing inflation, makes depressions inevitable by causing "malinvestment", i.e. by inducing businessmen to overinvest in "higher orders" of capital goods (machine tools, construction, etc.) and to underinvest in consumer goods.
The problem is that inflationary bank credit, when loaned to business, masquerades as pseudo-savings, and makes businessmen believe that there are more savings available to invest in capital goods production than consumers are genuinely willing to save. Hence, an inflationary boom requires a recession which becomes a painful but necessary process by which the market liquidates unsound investments and reestablishes the investment and production structure that best satisfies consumer preferences and demands.
Mises, and his follower Hayek, developed this cycle theory during the 1920s, on the basis of which Mises was able to warn an unheeding world that the widely trumpeted "New Era" of permanent prosperity of the 1920s was a sham, and that its inevitable result would be bank panic and depression. When Hayek was invited to teach at the London School of Economics in 1931 by an influential former student at Mises’s private seminar, Lionel Robbins, Hayek was able to convert most of the younger English economists to this perspective. On a collision course with John Maynard Keynes and his disciples at Cambridge, Hayek demolished Keynes’s Treatise on Money (1930), but lost the battle and most of his followers to the tidal wave of the Keynesian Revolution that swept the economic world after the publication of Keynes’s General Theory in 1936.
The policy prescriptions for business cycles of Mises-Hayek and of Keynes were diametrically opposed. During a boom period, Mises counseled the immediate end of all bank credit and monetary expansion; and, during a recession, he advised strict laissez-faire, allowing the readjustment forces of the recession to work themselves out as rapidly as possible.
Not only that: for Mises the worst form of intervention would be to prop up prices or wage rates, causing unemployment, to increase the money supply, or to boost government spending in order to stimulate consumption. For Mises, the recession was a problem of under-saving, and over-consumption, and it was therefore important to encourage savings and thrift rather than the opposite, to cut government spending rather than increase it. It is clear that, from 1936 on Mises was totally in opposition to the worldwide fashion in macroeconomic policy.
Socialism-communism had triumphed in Russia and in much of Europe during and after World War I, and Mises was moved to publish his famous article, "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" (1920, text), in which he demonstrated that it would be impossible for a socialist planning board to plan a modern economic system; furthermore, no attempt at artificial "markets" would work, since a genuine pricing and costing system requires an exchange of property titles, and therefore private property in the means of production.
Mises developed the article into his book Socialism (1922, text), a comprehensive philosophical and sociological, as well as economic critique which still stands as the most thorough and devastating demolition of socialism ever written. Mises’s Socialism converted many prominent economists and social philosophers out of socialism, including Hayek, the German Wilhelm Röpke[2], and the Englishman Lionel Robbins.
In the United States, the publication of the English translation of Socialism in 1936 attracted the admiration of the prominent economic journalist Henry Hazlitt, who reviewed it in the New York Times, and converted one of America’s most prominent and learned Communist fellow-travelers of the period, J.B. Matthews, to a Misesian position and to opposition to all forms of socialism.
Socialists throughout Europe and the United States worried about the problem of economic calculation under socialism for about fifteen years, finally pronouncing the problem solved with the promulgation of the "market socialism" model of the Polish economist Oskar Lange in 1936. Lange returned to Poland after World War II to help plan Polish Communism. The collapse of socialist planning, in Poland and the other Communist countries in 1989, left Establishment economists across the ideological spectrum, all of whom bought the Lange "solution", mightily embarrassed.
Some prominent socialists, such as Robert Heilbroner, have had the grace to admit publicly that "Mises was right" all along (the phrase "Mises was Right" was the title of a panel at the annual 1990 meeting of the Southern Economic Association at New Orleans).[3]
If socialism was an economic catastrophe, government intervention could not work, and would tend to lead inevitably to socialism. Mises elaborated these insights in his Critique of Interventionism (1929, text), and set forth his political philosophy of laissez-faire liberalism in his Liberalism (1927; text, pdf).
In adition to setting himself against all the political trends of the twentieth century, Mises combated with equal fervor and eloquence what he considered the disastrous dominant philosophical and methodological trends, in economics and other disciplines. These included positivism, relativism, historicism, polylogism” the idea that each race and gender has its own "logic" and therefore cannot communicate with other groups), and all forms of irrationalism and denial of objective truth. Mises also developed what he considered to be the proper methodology of economic theory--logical deduction from evident axioms, which he labeled "praxeology", and he leveled trenchant critiques of the growing tendency in economics and other disciplines to replace praxeology and historical understanding by unrealistic mathematical models and statistical manipulations.
In the United States
Emigrating to the United States in 1940, Mises’s first two books in English were important and influential. His Omnipotent Government (1944; text) was the first book to challenge the then-standard Marxian view that fascism and Nazism were imposed upon their nations by big business and the "capitalist class". His Bureaucracy (1944; text) was a still unsurpassed analysis of why government operation must necessarily be “bureaucratic” and suffer from all the ills of bureaucracy.
Mises’s most monumental achievement was his Human Action (1949), the first comprehensive treatise on economic theory written since the first World War. Here Mises took up the challenge of his own methodology and research program and elaborated an integrated and massive structure of economic theory on his own deductive, “praxeological” principles. Published in an era when economists and governments generally were totally dedicated to statism and Keynesian inflation, Human Action was unread by the economics profession. Finally, in 1957 Mises published his last major work, Theory and History (text, pdf), which, in addition to refutations of Marxism and historicism, set forth the basic differences and functions of theory and of history in economics as well as all the various disciplines of human action.
In the United States as in his native Austria, Mises could not find a paid post in academia. New York University, where he taught from until 1945 until his retirement at the age of 88 in 1969, would only designate him as Visiting Professor, and his salary had to be paid by the conservative-libertarian William Volker Fund until 1962, and after that by a consortium of free-market foundations and businessmen. Despite the unfavorable climate, Mises inspired a growing group of students and admirers, cheerfully encouraged their scholarship, and himself continued his remarkable productivity.
Mises was also sustained by and worked together with free-market and libertarian admirers. From its origin in 1946 until his death, Mises was a part-time staff member of the Foundation for Economic Education at Irvington-on-Hudson, New York; and he was in the 1950s an economic advisor to the National Association of Manufacturers (NAM) working with their laissez-faire wing which finally lost out to the tide of "enlightened" statism.
As a free trader and a classical liberal in the tradition of Cobden, Bright, and Spencer, Mises was a libertarian who championed reason and individual liberty in personal as well as economic matters. As a rationalist and an opponent of statism in all its forms, Mises would never call himself a “conservative,” but rather a liberal in the nineteenth-century sense.
Indeed, Mises was politically a laissez-faire radical, who denounced tariffs, immigration restrictions, or governmental attempts to enforce morality. On the other hand, Mises was a staunch cultural and sociological conservative, who attacked egalitarianism, strongly denounced political feminism as a facet of socialism. In contrast to many conservative critics of capitalism, Mises held that personal morality and the nuclear family were both essential to, and fostered by, a system of free-market capitalism.
Mises’s influence was remarkable, considering the unpopularity of his epistemological and political views. His students of the 1920s, even those who later became Keynesians, were permanently stamped by a visible Misesian influence. These students included, in addition to Hayek and Robbins, Fritz Machlup[4] Gottfried von Haberler[5], Oskar Morgenstern, Alfred Schutz[6], Hugh Gaitskell, Howard S. Ellis, John Van Sickle, and Erich Voegelin.
In France, General DeGaulle’s major economic and monetary adviser, who helped swing France away from socialism, was Jacques Rueff, an old-friend and admirer of Mises. And part of post-World War II Italy’s shift away from socialism was due to its President Luigi Einaudi, a distinguished economist and long-time friend and free-market colleague of Mises. In the United States, Mises was scarcely as influential. Under less promising academic conditions, his students and admirers included Henry Hazlitt, Lawrence Fertig, Percy Greaves, Jr., Bettina Bien Graeves, Hans F. Sennholz, William H. Peterson[7], Louis M. Spadaro, Israel M. Kirzner, Ralph Raico, George Reisman, and Murray N. Rothbard. But Mises was able to build a remarkably strong and loyal following among businessmen and other non-academics; his massive and complex Human Action has sold extraordinarily well ever since the year of its original publication.
Since Mises’s death in New York City on October 10, 1973 at the age of 92, Misesian doctrine and influence has experienced a renaissance. The following year saw not only Hayek’s Nobel Prize for Misesian cycle theory, but also the first of many Austrian School conferences in the United States. Books by Mises have been reprinted and collections of his articles translated and published. Courses and programs in Austrian Economics have been taught and established throughout the country.
Taking the lead in this revival of Mises and in the study and expansion of Misesian doctrine has been the Ludwig von Mises Institute, founded by Llewellyn Rockwell, Jr. in 1982 and headquartered in Auburn, Alabama. The Mises Institute publishes scholarly journals and books, and offers courses in elementary, intermediate and advanced Austrian economics, which attract increasing numbers of students and professors. Undoubtedly, the collapse of socialism and the increased attractiveness of the free market have greatly contributed to this upsurge of popularity.
Original text written by Murray N. Rothbard, used with generous permission of the Mises Institute.
Curriculum Vitae
Academic Degrees
- Dr. Jur. (Doctorate of Law), University of Vienna, Austria (1906)
Academic Appointments
- Lecturer of Economics, Vienna Business Academy, Austria (1906-1912)
- Lecturer of Economics, University of Vienna, Austria (1913-1914)
- Associate Professor of Economics, University of Vienna, Austria (1919-1934)
- Professor of International Economic Relations, Graduate Institute of International Studies, Switzerland (1934-1940)
- Visiting Professor of Economics, National University of Mexico (1942)
- Visiting Professor of Economics, Graduate School of Business Administration, New York University (1945-1969)
- Visiting Professor of Economics, Plano University (1965-1971)
Other Positions
- Economic Councillor, Austrian Chamber of Commerce (1909-1934)
- Captain, Artillery Regiment, Austro-Hungarian Army, WWI (1914-1918)
- Director, Austrian Restitution-and-Settlements Office (1918-1920)
- Member, Association for Social Policy (1919-1933)
- Founder, Austrian Institute for Business Cycle Research (1927)
- Advisor, Foundation for Economic Education (1946-1973)
- Member, Economic Principles Commission, National Association of Manufacturers (1946)
- Co-Founder, Mont Pelerin Society (1947)
- Advisor, National Association of Manufacturers (1954-1955)
Awards
- Distinguished Service Award, Fellowship of Former Overseas Rotarians (1957)
- Austrian Decoration for Science and Art (1962)
- Distinguished Fellow Award, American Economics Association (1969)
Honorary Degrees
- Hon. LL.D., Grove City College (1957)
- Hon. LL.D., New York University (1963)
- Dr. rer. pol. h.c. (Honorary Doctorate of Political Science), University of Freiburg, Germany (1964)
Bibliography
- The Theory of Money and Credit (1912, enlarged US edition 1953)
- Nation, State, and Economy (1919)
- "Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth" (1920) (article)
- Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis (1922, 1932, 1951)
- Liberalismus (1927, 1962 – translated into English, with the new title The Free and Prosperous Commonwealth)
- A Critique of Interventionism (1929)
- Epistemological Problems of Economics (1933, 1960)
- Memoirs (1940)
- Interventionism: An Economic Analysis (1941, 1998)
- Omnipotent Government: The Rise of Total State and Total War (1944)
- Bureaucracy (1944, 1962)
- Planned Chaos (1947, added to 1951 edition of Socialism)
- Human Action: A Treatise on Economics (1949, 1963, 1966, 1996)
- Planning for Freedom (1952, enlarged editions in 1962, 1974, and 1980)
- The Anti-Capitalistic Mentality (1956)
- Theory and History: An Interpretation of Social and Economic Evolution (1957)
- The Ultimate Foundation of Economic Science (1962)
- The Historical Setting of the Austrian School of Economics (1969)
- Notes and Recollections (1978)
- The Clash of Group Interests and Other Essays (1978)
- On the Manipulation of Money and Credit (1978)
- The Causes of the Economic Crisis, reissue
- Economic Policy: Thoughts for Today and Tomorrow (1979, lectures given in 1959)
- Money, Method, and the Market Process (1990)
- Economic Freedom and Interventionism (1990)
- The Free Market and Its Enemies (2004, lectures given in 1951)
- Marxism Unmasked: From Delusion to Destruction (2006, lectures given in 1952)
- Ludwig von Mises on Money and Inflation (2010, lectures given in the 1960s)
See also
- The Essential von Mises
- Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism
- Political Economy, Public Policy and Monetary Economics
- Richard von Mises
- Analytic-synthetic distinction and Ludwig von Mises' response to the Kantian challenge
- Classical liberalism
- Contributions to liberal theory
- Liberalism in Austria
- Libertarianism
- List of Austrian scientists
- Mont Pelerin Society
- Karl Polanyi, whom von Mises debated leading to Polanyi's book The Great Transformation
- F. A. Hayek, important disciple of von Mises
- Wilhelm Röpke, important disciple of Mises
- Henry Hazlitt, important disciple of von Mises
- Max Eastman, important disciple of von Mises
- Israel Kirzner, important disciple of von Mises
- Hans Sennholz, important disciple of von Mises
- Murray Rothbard, important disciple of von Mises
- George Reisman, important disciple of von Mises
- Lew Rockwell, founder of Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Gitta Sereny, his stepdaughter
Further reading
- Hülsmann, Jörg Guido. Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism (Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institut, 2007) ISBN 978-1-933550-18-3
- Kirzner, Israel M. Ludwig von Mises: the man and his economics (2001)
- Eamonn Butler, Ludwig von Mises – A Primer, Institute of Economic Affairs (2010)
- Brian Doherty, Radicals for Capitalism: A Freewheeling History of the Modern American Libertarian Movement (2007)
- Richard M. Ebeling, Political Economy, Public Policy, and Monetary Economics: Ludwig von Mises and the Austrian Tradition, (London/New York: Routledge, 2010) 354 pages, ISBN 978-0-415-77951-7.
- Richard M. Ebeling, "Ludwig von Mises: The Political Economist of Liberty, Part II", (The Freeman, June 2006)
- Richard M. Ebeling, "Ludwig von Mises: The Political Economist of Liberty, Part I", (The Freeman, May 2006)
- Richard M. Ebeling,"Ludwig von Mises and the Vienna of His Time, Part II", (The Freeman, April 2005)
- Richard M. Ebeling, "Ludwig von Mises and the Vienna of His Time, Part I", (The Freeman, March 2005)
- Richard M. Ebeling, "Austrian Economics and the Political Economy of Freedom", (The Freeman, June 2004)
- Hülsmann, Jörg Guido (2007). Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute. ISBN 978-1-933550-18-3. http://mises.org/document/3295/Mises-The-Last-Knight-of-Liberalism. Retrieved 16 May 2012.
- David Gordon (2011-02-23) Mises's Epistemology, Ludwig von Mises Institute
- Margit von Mises, My Years With Ludwig von Mises, Arlington House, 1976, rereleased in 1984 by Libertarian Press. ISBN 0-915513-00-5
- Ron Paul, "Mises and Austrian economics: A personal view" The Ludwig von Mises Institute of Auburn University (1984), 31 pages.
- Murray N. Rothbard, "Mises. Ludwig Edler von," The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, 1987, v. 3, pp. 479–80.
- "A Tribute to Ludwig Von Mises". A list of works by and on Ludwig Von Mises by the Foundation for Economic Education.
References
- ↑ Greaves, Bettina Bien (January 1995). Ludwig von Mises (1881-1973): A Prophet Without Honor in His Own Land. 45. http://www.thefreemanonline.org/columns/ludwig-von-mises-1881-1973-a-prophet-without-honor-in-his-own-land/.
- ↑ Shawn Ritenour. "Wilhelm Röpke (1899-1966): Humane Economist", Mises Institute, referenced 2009-05-24.
- ↑ "The Man Who Told the Truth", Reason, 1990. Retrieved on April 4 2009.
- ↑ Mark Thornton. "Biography of Fritz Machlup (1902-1983)", Mises Institute, referenced 2009-05-24.
- ↑ "Between Mises and Keynes An Interview with Gottfried von Haberler (1900-1995)", The Austrian Economics Newsletter Spring 2000 Volume 20, Number 1, referenced 2009-04-27.
- ↑ Peter Kurrild-Klitgaard. "The Viennese Connection: Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School"(pdf), The Quarterly Journal Of Austrian Economics Vol.6, no.2, referenced 2009-05-24.
- ↑ "William H. Peterson", Mises Institute, referenced 2009-05-25.
Links
![]() |
Wikiquote has a collection of quotations related to: Ludwig von Mises |
- Books and Essays by Mises (complete texts)
- The complete Mises bibliography
- The Mises Quotation Machine
- Mises: The Last Knight of Liberalism (pdf) by Jörg Guido Hülsmann
- Who was Mises? by Jörg Guido Hülsmann
- Tributes to Mises by Economists, Journalists, and Others
- The Story of the Lost Papers
- The Great Depression: Mises vs. Fisher (pdf) by Mark Thornton, November 2008
- The Enduring Power of Bureaucracy by Marcia Sielaff, September 2010
- "Ludwig von Mises" (PDF) by F.A. Hayek, May 1977
- "The Cultural Thought of Ludwig von Mises" (PDF) by Jeffrey A. Tucker and Llewellyn H. Rockwell, Jr., Fall 1991
- "The Wisdom of Ludwig von Mises" by Stephan Kinsella, July 2006
- "Ludwig von Mises and the Austrian School of Economics" (PDF) by Jeffrey M. Herbener, 1991
- "The Ludwig von Mises Legacy: A Reality Check" by by J. H. Huebert, December 2002
- Ludwig von Mises on Wikipedia
- Audio by Ludwig von Mises (english and spanish transcription)
|
|